Michael Perelman gave a wide-ranging talk in Ankara called the
Anarchy of Globalization which focused on the local impact of
globalization. The presentation was wideranging and included a
discussion of the evolution of usage and theoretical concerns.
We’ve
extracted a section below, on the role of “free trade” agreements and
one of their not-widely-recognized side effects, that of weakening food
security. The case study is Mexico.
By Michael Perelman, a professor of economics at California State University, Chico who also writes at Unsettling Economics
Judging
by the official discourse about globalization, one might imagine that
we are witnessing a natural evolution of free trade that benefits
everybody touched by globalization, as in Thomas Friedman’s vision of
the flat world. In truth, much of the pressure to intensify
globalization does not necessarily come from market successes, but often
comes from disappointment in market outcomes. Dissatisfied that markets
were not providing sufficient profits, powerful states adopted a
strategy of pressuring their weaker counterparts to join in so called
free trade deals.
In fact, free trade is, at best, a secondary
consideration of the trade agreements. For example, tariffs on trade
between the U.S. and Europe are only 3.5 percent. A treaty to eliminate
such tariffs would not be of great importance certainly one that would
not involve strong diplomatic pressure and threats.
In contrast,
free trade agreements put enormous emphasis on intellectual property
agreements, which are antithetical to trade, in general, because they
grant monopoly status, which allows suppliers to set their own price
without competition. In this sense, intellectual property is a violation
of sacred market principles, according to which the price of a good
should be the cost of producing one more unit, what economists call
“marginal costs.”
Intellectual property, however, generally costs
virtually nothing to reproduce. Because of this violation of free market
principles inherent in intellectual property, libertarians including
libertarian economists had long opposed patents and copyrights, although
less so now that few libertarians are leery of excessive corporate
powers. Free trade treaties’ treatment of intellectual property is more
accurately described as a transfer of power, rather than a promotion of
free trade. Such intellectual property agreements can threaten public
health. For example, people in impoverished countries cannot afford the
exorbitant costs of pharmaceuticals. Diseases that could be relatively
easily contained have more room to spread.
Free trade treaties
include investment dispute provisions, adjudicated by a tribunal made up
of judges (generally with strong corporate ties). In other words, they
have a better understanding of corporate interests rather than a typical
body of law.
Under many such treaties, corporations have the
right to expect a static regulatory framework. In other words, the
tribunals can find new regulations illegal because a corporation could
not have predicted them when it first began planning its investment. At
the same time, corporations are free to change their corporate policies.
There is a surge of cases in which corporations have sued under this
provision. Even when a country’s preexisting regulations prevent an
investment, such creating a toxic waste, the company can take the
government before a tribunal. They almost always win such cases. And,
yes, a panel of supposedly neutral judges actually permitted the toxic
waste dump in question to go ahead.
In effect, this new legal
structure elevates elevated to the status of an independent government,
or perhaps even a higher status, in that corporations can limit what a
government might do, while governments lose significant power to limit
what a corporation might do.
Of course, a real free trade
agreement, regarding what most people understand as free trade would be a
very simple matter, consisting of a paragraph or two. Instead, such
arrangements, supposedly made in the spirit of free trade, are actually
thousands of pages of severe restrictions on public policy measures in
the weaker countries that are pressured to accept these impositions. But
free trade treaties even limit strong countries because political
leaders want to free business from regulations. They may do so because
it is in their interests rather than the people whom they supposedly
represent.
For example, signatories of free trade agreements
surrender their right to regulate imports of cigarettes or junk food,
which might affect the health of their populations. The United States is
particularly insistent in demanding that no country can prevent the
marketing of genetically modified seeds or the crops that Monsanto and
other suppliers want to sell around the world. These so called free
trade agreements also regulate the regulation of virtually everything
that an independent government might do. They demand that states adopt
regulatory structures regarding intellectual property rights or finance
that please the dominant powers.
Such demands should not be
surprising because in the United States, free trade agreements are
actually written by corporate interests. Congress has no say in their
content. Representatives can only vote to accept or reject the treaties.
The final product, which might be celebrated in board rooms across the
United States, requires poor countries to abandon all sorts of legal
rights, while exposing their economy to market forces that can overwhelm
their fragile economics.
The proposed Trans Pacific Partnership
also seems to have been crafted with geopolitical policy rather than
trade in mind by bringing many nations into the United States’ orbit,
while excluding China. The hope is that once the treaty is in place,
China will want to join even though the country had no say in the
drafting. Should that happen, then the Chinese government would lose
most of its control over the economy. In the meantime, corporate
interests are busy writing this so called free trade agreements in so
much secrecy that even members of Congress are not permitted to read
what was being proposed. Recently, after strong protests both in and out
of Congress, the Obama administration finally opened a tiny window,
allowing congressional representatives to read a single chapter of the
agreement, while forbidding them to make any record of what they have
read or even to discuss it with others. The public at large remains
completely in the dark, except for a few parts that whistleblowers have
leaked. But then again, secrecy is one of the great benefits of
globalization.
The agreement has little to do with trade. Instead,
it gives wide ranging rights to corporations, while prohibiting states
from enforcing regulations of health and safety, finance, the
environment, and virtually anything else that might inconvenience
business. Member states that violate this treaty receive severe
punishment.
The Obama administration is pressuring Congress to
vote on the unread agreement without the option to offer any amendments.
Meanwhile, domestic businesses interests are more than happy to see
restrictions limiting the state’s power to regulate them. So much for
free trade! unless the meaning of free trade is expanded to include the
votes of compliant politicians who serve corporate interests.
If
anarchy constitutes the absence of government, this aspect of
globalization might seem to be a move toward a special kind of anarchy
what may be called anarchism for the rich and powerful.
Within
this globalized anarchy, weakened states are incapable of addressing
serious global problems, which require globalized responses. The most
obvious example would be climate change. Largely because of the
resistance of domestic business from accepting any responsibility for
climate change, states are paralyzed in the face of taking action. One
area in which governments do cooperate is in joining together to oppose
any regulations that might be useful in reducing climate change. The
effectiveness of this cohesive bloc suggests how much good statewide
achieve.
Of course, not all states sign on to this defense of
inaction. For example, small island states, such as the Maldives, face
existential risk from rising oceans submerging their nations. However,
when the Maldives attempted to draw world attention to the danger it
faced at the international conference on climate change, coincidentally,
the government was suddenly overthrown: a different form of anarchy,
suggesting that many states still exercise enormous power, but they
cannot use that same power when it is not in the interests of even more
powerful corporations.
In 1969, Charles Kindleberger presciently
observed the rise of corporate power relative to the government within
the context of international trade, predicting, “the nation state is
just about through as an economic unit.”
More recently Wolfgang
Reinicke went further, concluding: “Global corporate networks challenge a
state’s internal sovereignty by altering the relationship between the
private and public sectors. By inducing corporations to fuse national
markets, globalization creates an economic geography that subsumes
multiple political geographies. A government no longer has a monopoly of
the legitimate power over the territory within which corporations
operate, as the rising incidence of regulatory and tax arbitrage
attests.”
Reinicke even suggested that this globalization was
trending toward a form of anarchy. If anarchy constitutes the absence of
government, this aspect of globalization might seem to be a move toward
a special kind of anarchy what may be called anarchism for the rich and
powerful.
In his “Politics as a Vocation,” Max Weber suggested a
broader interpretation of this seeming anarchism. After citing Trotsky
saying, “Every state is founded on force,” he went on to note, “The
state is considered the sole source of the ‘right’ to use violence.”
From Weber’s perspective, globalization is actually empowering the
state.
The same progress in information technologies that that
created a utopian belief in the possibility of worldwide democracy,
facilitated the growth of globalization that made the new anarchy
possible is also being used around the world to rapidly increase
authoritarian powers, which now have the capacity to monitor virtually
everything that ordinary people do. So, while one part of society enjoys
the privacy that this new regime of secrecy provides, the rest of
society has been rapidly losing what little remains of its privacy.
In
effect, alongside the global redistribution of wealth and income,
globalization also seems to be redistributing people’s rights. So far, I
have been unable to detect any effective response to this troubling
trend. What then, does free trade really mean?
Globalization of Food
Food,
of course, has long been an integral part of the world of international
politics. As far back as the beginning of historical records,
belligerent countries have attempted to shut off food supplies for their
enemies an early form of de globalization. The history of international
food politics in the United States makes a fascinating study: with the
recovery from the Great Depression, massively increased food demands
needed for fighting the Second World War, together with enormous
technical advances in food production in the postwar period, left the
country saddled with substantial food surpluses. To dump the surpluses
abroad, Congress enacted Public Law 480, which allowed countries to
purchase food with their own currencies. At first, this policy displayed
a humanitarian veneer, which seemed like a win win policy. Countries
could get needed food and the cost of maintaining surpluses would
diminish.
By 1957, Sen. Hubert Humphrey, later Vice President of
the United States, let the cat out of the bag. Testifying before
Congress about the program, Humphrey gloated: “I have heard … that
people may become dependent on us for food. I know this is not supposed
to be good news. To me that was good news, because before people can do
anything they have got to eat. And if you are looking for a way to get
people to lean on you and to be dependent on you, in terms of their
cooperation with you, it seems to me that food dependence would be
terrific.” Part of the attractiveness of this dependence was the high
priority given to efforts to stamp out Communist influence, especially
in Asia. PL 480 exports increased by roughly 40 percent during the
Kennedy administration. George McGovern, then director of the Food for
Peace program and a former bomber pilot during the Second World War,
believed that food aid was “a far better weapon than a bomber in our
competition with the Communists for influence in the developing world.”
A Mexican Laboratory
The
experience of Mexico provides a striking example of the effect of this
perverted form of free trade in food. In the wake of the North American
Free Trade Agreement (1986), heavily subsidized American agriculture,
equipped with the most modern technology devastated Mexican agriculture,
setting off a massive migration out of agriculture and out of Mexico.
Similarly,
one can only wonder how much the Mexicans lost when the free trade
agreement with the United States left Mexican consumers and farmers more
dependent on relatively homogeneous, industrialized corn instead of the
wide variety of indigenous corn that had been developed over centuries
in Mexico. Ultimately, the homogeneity of a crop leaves it more
vulnerable. A 1970 outbreak of corn leaf blight proved that point, by
ravaging the U.S. corn harvest.
The loss of the heterogeneity of
Mexican corn is another example of unintentional globalization. Because
corn is such an important crop around the world, the plant’s loss of
genetic diversity affects much of the rest of the world. Eventually,
some pathogen will evolve a method to take advantage of some genetic
weakness in a dominant strain of corn.
Traditionally, corn breeders
could themselves take advantage of the genetic heteroge
neity of Mexican
corn to find some particular strain that could fend off the pathogen.
The inevitable homogenization of Mexican corn with the disappearance of
small growers, who maintained the local strains, will deprive future
generations of farmers of traditional methods of defense.
As
mentioned earlier, a major priority of the free trade agreements that
are currently being negotiated is a restriction on countries’ capacity
to regulate the use of genetically modified organisms, either by
restricting imports or preventing their farmers from planting such
crops. Farmers also will be prohibited from replanting the GMO seeds
they buy from the United States, something that resonates with Hubert
Humphrey’s unpleasant celebration of dependence. Such policies mean that
the world will become increasingly dependent on a handful of seed
companies, which would displace the previously heterogeneous population
of seeds. Such genetic homogenization of crops ultimately poses a threat
to the world food supply.
While trade agreements limit the rights
of nations, such as Mexico, to help their farmers, farmers in
California receive highly subsidized water transfers to be able to plant
cotton on arid land, which would otherwise be unsuitable for cotton. As
a result, the Colorado River no longer reaches Mexico, which badly
needs that river’s water. The resulting U.S. cotton harvest has managed
to snuff out the demand for a good deal of African cotton production,
thereby ensuring, or even increasing, poverty there.
No hay comentarios:
Publicar un comentario